A Judeo-Christian defense of free enterprise?
A Judeo-Christian defense of free enterprise?
—The Christian alternative?⤒🔗
In a previous article, An Introduction to A Christian Perspective on Economics (Reformed Perspective, July 1982), I noted that the question "Free enterprise or government control?" was one of the important outstanding economic issues that we as Christians should seek to answer. In the meantime, with, for example, the government's purchase of BP Canada and the possible large-scale investment in the financially troubled Dome, the debate on the degree of state ownership goes on as actively as ever. The Auditor-General's recent revelation that 306 federal crown corporations employ more people than the government proper and his description of this group as "a hole in the taxpayer's pocket" and as "an enormous iceberg, floating lazily in the foggy Atlantic; silent, majestic, awesome," is likely to increase the level of debate.
Moreover, in the current depressed economic circumstances many voices are raised demanding even more direct government action to increase employment, to reduce interest rates, to prop up troubled industries to save jobs, and to encourage new industries, i.e., to pick and support the "winners." Christians are not immune either froth the urge to suggest that the government "do something." In the November issue of Reformed Perspective, for instance, author after author pointed out that not enough was being done to save the environment and protect us from the various toxic substances. Thus, the extent of government ownership and control is an issue as relevant as ever — an issue that Christians also must come to grips with.
I have argued previously that authors like Tom Rose and Hebdon Taylor failed to prove their contention that free enterprise is obviously the Christian alternative. I was most interested, therefore, when I came across a new book called Free Enterprise — A Judeo-Christian Defense. Its author, Harold Lindsell, categorically claims (p. 51) that "free enterprise as known and practiced in the Western world ... is derived from the Judeo-Christian tradition which, in turn, locates its authority in the Old and New Testaments."
However, after reading the book, I was disappointed. Although it does many things, I believe that the book does not do what its title promises: provide a Christian defense of free enterprise.
If that is so, why review this book publicly? First, if I am wrong, setting out my criticism may serve as a discussion focus to help clarify the position of Lindsell and others. Secondly, if free enterprise can, indeed, not be defended as the Christian alternative, it is important that Christians recognize this. If the Bible does not unambiguously support free enterprise, claims that it does are likely to cast doubt upon the total Christian message.
In reviewing the book, I will focus on the question, "Does Lindsell provide a Christian defense of free enterprise?" I will put forward two points. First, Lindsell incorrectly simplifies the argument to a choice between unrestricted free enterprise, on the one hand, and communism, on the other. Consequently, a lot of his arguments are not valid as a defense of free enterprise. Secondly, the Scriptural proofs put forward by Lindsell show only that the Bible accepts free enterprise — not that we must support it.
A Simplified Argument←↰⤒🔗
a. Extreme distinctions←↰⤒🔗
First, then, I believe that Lindsell's argument is seriously weakened by his extreme black/white definitions of free enterprise and socialism. The chart on this page sets out how I previously described the various economic systems. While the chart shows three columns, reality is probably better illustrated by a continuous line with extreme free enterprise on the one end, totalitarian systems such as communism on the other end, and various forms of the mixed economy in between.
Lindsell in his book, however, expresses the view that "there are basically only two economic systems" (p. 47). He focusses only on that form of socialism set out in the third column of the chart and, disregarding the existence of other totalitarian states, takes communism as representative of all forms of socialism. He rightly condemns communism as based on the views of Karl Marx — atheism, dialectic materialism, class struggle, and "democratic centralism" — but unreservedly applies this condemnation to all possible forms of socialism.
b. Utopian socialism←↰⤒🔗
He does mention, in passing, the "utopian" socialists who hope to reach the objective of communal ownership and control by the use of "ballots rather than bullets," and who do not share the Marxian basis. He appears to be thinking primarily of the nineteenth century collectives, which, he says, have now disappeared due to the failure of socialism to work in practice. The fact that the Hutterites, who also believe in communal ownership, still prosper in Canada has apparently escaped his attention. Since Lindsell believes that the only form of socialism which offers a serious challenge to free enterprise is the Marxist variety, he concludes that "it is useless to concern ourselves with utopian socialism."
c. The mixed economy←↰⤒🔗
Lindsell discards from consideration also the central column of our chart, the mixed economy. He recognizes that some of the nations of the world, such as Britain and Sweden, those known as welfare states, have a mixed economy which combines some socialism and free enterprise. He concludes, however (p. 47), that "this sort of hybrid system is ultimately nonviable, for it violates the basic principles of both free enterprise and socialism and cannot long survive the inevitable struggle for supremacy by these competing and antithetical ideologies." This conclusion, however, is unsupported.
d. Free enterprise←↰⤒🔗
His quick rejection of the mixed economy is the more puzzling in that he espouses a very strict definition of free enterprise. Free enterprise, according to Lindsell (p. 16), is based on the "intrinsic right of people to the ownership, control and use of private property" and "carries with it the right of those who have goods or services for sale to set whatever price they wish for the sale of what they have to offer." In discussing the role of government (p. 105), he details a series of government excesses without any suggestion as to any legitimate government activities. The reader must conclude, therefore, that Lindsell accepts no government restriction of any kind to the right of private ownership and no government involvement in and control of the economy.
I realize that Lindsell does talk about "free enterprise controlled by the Judeo-Christian ethic." That is, he argues (p. 9) that "free enterprise without the spiritual component common to Judeo-Christian tradition is deficient." This spiritual component is altruism, the concept of neighborly love which I previously noted to be one of the Biblical principles that are particularly relevant for the study of economics. Lindsell details this as, for instance (p. 118), "Producers of goods and services will not lie, cheat, or steal. They will not envy competitors who do a better job, nor will they be covetous. Unfair economic gimmicks such as cartels and monopolies will not be used."
However, Lindsell fails to show that free enterprise limited in such a way exists or can exist. Rather, he himself recognizes that "what measure of free enterprises exists in the West is largely dominated by the secular humanism of this age." He further accepts (p. 48, 74) that "man is not fundamentally good, nor is ever going to be" and (p. 92) even raises (without answering) the question, "How can one impose the Judeo-Christian viewpoint on those who do not accept it?"
Thus, while it would be very attractive to see free enterprise controlled by Christian altruism, that is just not the case now — if it ever has been. Altruism is not inherent in free enterprise. At best, it might be possible to say that in the past, when Judeo-Christian principles were more generally adhered to, the excesses caused by free enterprise were less noticeable. However, even that may be in doubt.
We are, therefore, left with Lindsell's contention that even without altruism, "free enterprise, despite the fallen nature of man, is distinctly preferable to socialism!"
e. Reality rejected←↰⤒🔗
With unrestricted free enterprise as one alternative and communism as the other, Lindsell, in my view, fails to deal with the reality of the industrial Western world — that world in which we live. In Canada, as in most other countries of the Western world, governments directly and through crown corporations own a significant share of resources and means of production. Yet, a major part of the economy still functions through the marketplace, although that marketplace is at many points restricted and regulated by governments. In these countries, we find legitimate socialist parties of many stripes, some of whom have governed with a certain degree of success, for example, the New Democrats in several Canadian provinces, Labour in the U.K., and Social Democrats in Germany. Although no doubt including Marxists in their left wings, these parties do not espouse force to obtain their goals and do not generally strive to nationalize all resources. And so, the world we live in contains many countries which have mixed economies in which the largest bone of contention is, "Which way should we move: toward more government ownership and direction or toward more reliance on the market system?"
If it were true that only the two extreme alternatives existed, it would be true that arguments against communism would automatically be arguments for free enterprise. That is, the argument that communism must be rejected because communist countries restrict freedom of religion would automatically be an argument in favor of free enterprise. Since such an extreme dichotomy is not valid, Lindsell's vigorous attack upon communism, while providing strong support for the rejection of that system, does not provide, as is claimed, a "Judeo-Christian" defense of free enterprise.
Unconvincing Scriptural Proofs←↰⤒🔗
a. Human greed←↰⤒🔗
When we look at the actual Christian arguments that Lindsell brings forward in defense of free enterprise, we encounter first his contention that "free enterprise is far and away the better economic system to contain human greed." If this claim were correct, Christians should certainly favor free enterprise, since greed and selfishness are clearly evidences of sin. Unfortunately, the evidence to prove this contention is missing.
The purported justification for this statement is that under the free enterprise system people who purchase commodities are kings and queens of the marketplace; the success or failure of the producer depends on his meeting the wants of the consumer in the best possible way.
How providing the consumer everything he wants (at least in so far as he can afford) restricts human greed, is something I fail to understand! The market system is no doubt more efficient than socialism, but to call a system that is based on man's self-interest the best to restrict that interest seems far-fetched!
b. The inalienability of private property←↰⤒🔗
A recurrent theme in Lindsell's argument is his concept of the "inalienability (that is, non-separability and transferability) of private property." He makes the unsupported claim (p. 53) that private property, like the law of gravity, "is a given in nature by the creative fiat of nature's God." This analogy, however, is deficient, since the communists have, by and large, been able to abolish this so-called natural law of property while no one has as yet managed to abolish the law of gravity.
He argues further (p. 54) that this right of private property means no less than that no "law passed by a majority or the unanimous consent of a legislature can expropriate property from the owner of that property." He claims that the commandment, "Thou shalt not steal," applies also to the government in the normal exercise of its duties. While I agree that government expropriation without fair compensation can be characterized as stealing, I believe that to call all expropriation stealing is going too far. That would mean that very few new roads, railways, airports, etc., could be built. In fact, it would mean that no taxes could be collected. After all, what is the difference between taking a man's money and a man's land?
However, Christ Himself in Matthew 22:21 teaches us to "Give to Caesar what is Caesar's," and the payment of taxes is taken as normal in both Old and New Testaments. Under the kings of Israel, taxes (as well as expropriation of property) were common, as we see, for instance, in Samuel's warning in 1 Samuel 8, "He will take the best of your fields and vineyards and olive orchards and give them to his servants," etc. Certainly, Solomon imposed heavy taxes to build the temple and his palaces. There is no indication that the Bible refers to this as stealing. Overall, I doubt that the inalienability of private property over against government can be substantiated on the basis of the eighth commandment.
c. Other Scriptural arguments for private property←↰⤒🔗
Lindsell's other Scriptural "proofs" appear equally questionable.
The apportionment of land (p. 56) to the people of Israel and the protection of these inheritances through the Jubilee law certainly shows the acceptance of private property in the Old Testament. But are not these Old Testament Mosaic laws now fulfilled? While it is evidence that the Bible does not reject the holding of private property, does it also mean that the Bible teaches that everyone today must own property or at least have the opportunity to do so? If so, would this not also mean that we must go back to apportioning of family inheritances and accepting the law of Jubilee? Moreover, with its inherent prohibition against selling the family land, God's law for Israel can hardly be characterized as unrestricted free enterprise!
In fact, evidence of government ownership and involvement in "industry" can also be found in the Old Testament. See, for instance, the account of Solomon's activities in 2 Chronicles 8, in particular his joint trading venture to send ships to Ophir. And surely Joseph's management of the Egyptian economy can hardly be described as free enterprise!
Lindsell's "evidence" from Jesus's teachings (pp. 59-63), the parables of the tenant farmers (Mark 12:1-12, etc.), the workers in the harvest (Matthew 20:1-16), the prodigal son (Luke 15:11-32), and that of the talents (Luke 19:11-32), all show that Jesus accepts ownership of private property as being quite normal. No case is made, however, that all property must be held by private individuals and that governments should not hold some or even quite a lot of property.
Similarly, the history of the early church (p. 64) and Ananias and Sapphira clearly shows that Ananias did not have to donate his property to the Church. However, to say that "it places the imprimatur of the apostles on free enterprise" is stretching the point. Just because something is allowed, does not mean it is required or even encouraged. The other references from the New Testament which Lindsell brings forward, while supporting the acceptability of wealth and the existence of diversity of man, provides no support for unrestricted free enterprise as the Christian economic system.
Inconclusive←↰⤒🔗
We are left, then, with the practical arguments for free enterprise as Lindsell sets out, for instance, in his chapter entitled "Economics." Lindsell himself stresses these material advantages, e.g., p. 160, "Free enterprise (capitalism) is distinctly preferable to socialism. It will do a better job in meeting and improving the material conditions of men than socialism." In fact, on the last page he concludes that the book can be best summed up by the words:
You cannot bring about prosperity by discouraging thrift. You cannot strengthen the weak by weakening the strong. You cannot help the wage earner by pulling down the wage payer. You cannot further the brotherhood of man by encouraging class hatred. You cannot keep out of trouble by spending more than you earn. You cannot build character and courage by taking away man's initiative and independence. You cannot help men permanently by doing for them what they could and should do for themselves.
If that is really the theme of a book that claims to be a "Judeo-Christian defense" of free enterprise, where is the Judeo-Christian part in this defense?
We must conclude that, while Lindsell's book presents a strong condemnation of communism, while it provides a practical defense of free enterprise, it does not do what it promises to do, and that is to provide a Judeo-Christian defense of free enterprises. The case that the Bible requires a Christian to support free enterprise has yet to be proven. Personally, I doubt that it can be.
We can agree from a practical, neutral perspective that free enterprises is desirable. We must recognize, as Lindsell does, that man is fallen in sin. It follows that the excesses inherent in free enterprise ought to be curbed. We know that God has given government to control the depravity of man (see Article 36 of the Belgic Confession). It is our task as Christians to point out to governments what these restrictions should be. Let us continue to study so that we can discuss and agree on the necessary restrictions. But let us not claim Biblical support for positions that we cannot defend and, by so doing, leave the true Christian message open to doubt.
Add new comment